Unpacking the drivers of inequality
The relationship between growth and income inequality is more complex than the one between growth and poverty, and has been the subject of considerable study.
An early contribution in the 1950s by Nobel Prize-winning economist
Simon Kuznets, for instance, noted that at least two forces tended to
increase inequality over time. One was the concentration of savings in
the upper-income groups; he observed that in the United States the
wealthiest 5 percent of the population accounted for close to two-thirds
of total savings.
A second factor, which has been a universal characteristic of development over the past century, was the gradual shift away from agriculture. Between 1991 and 2001, for instance, more than 8 million people left agriculture in India. Between 1965 and 2000 the share of the labor force employed in agriculture fell from 49 to 21 percent in Brazil, from 26 to 5 percent in Japan, from 55 to 11 percent in Korea, from 81 to 47 percent in China, and it fell to 2 percent in the United States.
As people moved from villages to cities, from agriculture into industry,
they moved from a low productivity sector to one of higher productivity
and this heightened income disparities. Incomes tended to be more equal
in agriculture, but as people moved to the cities this meant the share
of the population where income was more unequal increased.
Other factors were also at work, some of them exerting an influence in
the opposite direction. One was the increasing role of government and
the implementation of policies intended to reduce income disparities,
whether through inheritance taxes, mechanisms for social protection, or
critically, the extension of publicly financed education to large
segments of the population, including girls.
In some countries—particularly in East Asia—land reform also strongly
contributed to diminished income disparities and, may have unleashed
rapid economic growth and convergence. The role of government policy
implied that, often, there was a growing distinction (or gap) between
inequality in living standards and inequality in incomes,
with the former often boosted through the redistributive attributes of
the government budget. Demography and migration had an impact on the
distribution of income too.
At least as important was the impact of technology and the dynamic
forces associated with industrialization. New technologies, and
associated processes meant that those with the skills to handle new
machinery or read instruction manuals—the vast majority of them
men—could command much higher wages, and this inevitably led to a
widening of income disparities between the genders.
Moreover, this phenomenon was self-reinforcing. Those who, because of
their skills commanded higher wages, could afford to get loans to start
new ventures and save more, accumulated a growing share of the country’s
wealth, something that provided additional opportunities for profitable
investments and create new companies. In countries with weak
institutions, ineffective regulations and poor law enforcement, this
often translated into expanded opportunities for the unscrupulous,
particularly those with access to the levers of political power.
The expansion of huge wealth stemming from corruption has surely been a
regular feature of economic development during the past couple of
centuries. Where growing income disparities were partly (or mainly) due
to corruption and the abuse of power the result often was growing social
tensions, political instability or, at the extreme, civil disturbances.
However, absent corruption, the result was often the creation of new
industries and the emergence of a powerful culture of innovation.
The relationship between education, training and a skilled labor force
and inequality is strong and dynamic. At one level, as education spreads
and a growing share of the population partakes of its benefits, one
might expect a leveling off of income inequality. There is evidence that
this is exactly what happened in England in the 19th
century, widening at first as the process of industrialization got
underway and leveling off before the end of the century. (Benjamin
Friedman argues in “The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth” that
“Karl Marx’s claim that capitalism inevitably leads to ever increasing
misery of the working classes, and hence to an explosive polarization of
society, resulted from Marx’s myopic extrapolation of the widening
inequality that accompanied England’s economic growth in the first half
of the nineteenth century” (p. 349)).
However, there is no guarantee that this leveling off will be permanent.
Since technological change is relative, the arrival of new technologies
can, in principle, induce exactly the same sorts of changes which the
introduction of simpler technologies had on skills-based wage
differentials during earlier stages of the development process, leading,
yet again, to rising income disparities.
Friedman (2005) offers an interesting analysis of the impact of
outsourcing on income inequality. When an American manufacturer closes
its plant in the United States and shifts it to India, American workers’
job losses will be offset by job gains in India. While some US workers
may be able to find jobs elsewhere, others may not. Also, profits of the
company are likely to rise because of the lower labor costs and the net
impact, therefore, will be to widen inequality within the United
States. Moreover, because some workers in India will now be earning
wages well above the average in India, the closing of the plant in the
United States will also widen inequality within India. However,
inequality between the United States and India will have been
narrowed. Friedman then asks: “If India’s average income draws closer to
America’s, but in the process some Indians—in this example, the lucky
workers who get the new factory jobs—pull ahead of their neighbors, is
the net outcome a victory or a defeat for the cause of equality?”
We do not have a full understanding of the relative importance of all
these factors—accumulation of savings, the declining role of
agriculture, demography, government policy, migration, technological
change, and globalization, to name a few—in shaping the evolution of
income inequality. Some are obviously more amenable to change through
shifts in the content of policies. Others—technological change being
perhaps the leading example—are more exogenous in nature, responding to a
combination of human creativity, the profit motive and, only at the
margin, possibly government incentives and being, therefore, much more
unpredictable in its impact.
One can reasonably assume that the importance of these factors will vary
from country to country, depending on their stage of development, and
that that importance will shift over time, in reflection of structural
changes in the global economy. However, Kuznets was correct in arguing
that without better knowledge of the evolution of income inequality and
the factors that shape it, our own understanding of the process of
economic development would be undermined as would our capacity to
respond effectively to the challenges created by income divergence.